Testimony presented to the Small Business Roundtable on The
Future of Long-Term Care and Medicaid in Hagerstown, Maryland, July 10, 2006
before Chairman Donald Manzullo (R-16-IL) and Vice Chairman Roscoe Bartlett
(R-6-MD)
by
Stephen A. Moses, president, Center for Long-Term Care Reform, www.centerltc.com
Mr. Chairman Manzullo and Vice Chairman Bartlett, thank you
for the opportunity to testify before you today about Medicaid, long-term care
financing, and the impact of the Deficit Reduction Act of 2005 on those two
critical issues.
On February 8, 2006, President Bush signed into law the Deficit Reduction
Act of 2005 (DRA). Although the DRA
does not address all the problems nor implement all the solutions proposed by
the Center for Long-Term Care Reform, it does go a long way in the right
direction. Following is a summary
of the provisions of the DRA related to long-term care, an explanation of how
and why they advance the cause of rational long-term care financing policy, and
comments about what more needs to be done.
(Endnote 1)
It must be noted first that the
Deficit Reduction Act faces a legal challenge.
Several lawsuits have been brought in federal court challenging the
constitutionality of the DRA. A
Medicaid planning attorney in Alabama filed one of the suits; Public Citizen,
founded by Ralph Nader, filed another; a third was brought by members of
Congress. All of the suits
challenge the DRA on the grounds that, due to a clerical error, it was not
passed in identical form in both Houses of Congress.
Until this matter plays out in the courts, the DRA is presumed to be the
law of the land.
The DRA has three major sets of
provisions germane to long-term care. The
first set of provisions addresses Medicaid long-term care eligibility.
The second involves the long-term care insurance partnership program.
And the third applies to the provision of home and community-based
services under the Medicaid program.
THE DRA AND MEDICAID LTC ELIGIBILITY
The
Look Back Period
The DRA, most of the provisions of which were effective
upon enactment February 8, 2006, extends the look back period for asset
transfers from the previous three years to five years.
The Social Security Act imposes a Medicaid eligibility penalty when
assets are transferred for less than fair market value for the purpose of
qualifying for Medicaid. What has
changed is that the period of time state Medicaid programs are required to
"look back" and consider whether transfers qualify for the penalty has
been extended from three years to five years.
Note that this change is the latest in a series of laws
making Medicaid's transfer of assets restriction longer and stronger.
The process began with the Tax Equity and Financial Responsibility Act of
1982 which allowed states at their option to impose a transfer of assets penalty
of up to two years for assets improperly transferred within the previous two
years. The Medicare Catastrophic
Coverage Act of 1988 made the transfer of assets penalty mandatory for state
Medicaid programs to impose, extended the look back period to 30 months, and
increased the upside limit of the potential penalty to 30 months.
Finally, the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993 extended the look
back period to a full three years for general transfers and to five years for
transfers into a trust. Thus, the
DRA merely extends the look back period for general transfers to equal the same
period used since 1993 for transfers to trusts.
As always, the purpose of the look back and transfer of
assets eligibility penalty is to discourage inappropriate use of Medicaid's
scarce resource to fund long-term care for people who could have paid their own
way. The further ahead people have
to plan to give away their wealth to qualify for Medicaid benefits, the less
likely they will be to do so. A
five-year look back period is more likely to discourage intentional
self-impoverishment than a three-year period, but it probably is not enough to
prevent the practice altogether.
The average period of time from onset to death in
Alzheimer's Disease is eight years. When
it becomes obvious that an aging person is declining in physical or mental
capacity, future long-term care is easy to anticipate.
Thousands of Medicaid planners throughout the country advise people to
plan for this eventuality by divesting or sheltering their assets early.
The Congress should consider extending the transfer of assets look back
period to at least eight years. Few
people are willing to give up control of their wealth in anticipation of needing
long-term care in the future as long as they remain physically and mentally
healthy. At that earlier stage,
they are far more likely to consider and to qualify medically and financially
for private long-term care insurance. The
look back period for asset transfers done to qualify for public assistance in
Germany is ten years. Ironically,
the United States, with its supposedly market-based health care system, is more
lenient in this regard than Germany's social insurance system for funding
long-term care.
The
Transfer of Assets Eligibility Penalty and the Half-a-Loaf Strategy
The Medicaid eligibility penalty for transferring assets
applies only to assets transferred for less than fair market value and for the
purpose of qualifying for the program. The
penalty period in months is equal to the amount of assets improperly transferred
divided by the average cost of a private nursing home in the state.
For example, $100,000 divested without compensation for the purpose of
becoming eligible for Medicaid would incur a 20-month penalty if the average
cost of a nursing home in the state is $5,000 per month.
But this full penalty as intended by Congress was rarely imposed.
The reason is that under previous law, the penalty period began at the
date the assets were transferred. This
fact gave rise to the widely recommended "half-a-loaf" Medicaid
planning strategy. In other words,
don't give away the whole $100,000 at once and incur the full 20-month penalty.
Rather, give away $50,000, incur a ten-month penalty, spend the other
$50,000 as you choose or convert it to an exempt asset, bide your time and apply
for Medicaid ten months later without having spent any of your own money for
long-term care.
The Deficit Reduction Act eliminated this
"half-a-loaf" strategy by changing the date of imposition of the
transfer of assets penalty from the date of the transfer to the date at which
the transferor would have otherwise been eligible if the law hadn't changed,
usually the date of nursing home admission or Medicaid application.
Thus, in the example above, the individual who transferred $50,000 and
waited ten months would find himself or herself vulnerable under the new law to
a ten-month penalty at the very time that the penalty under the previous law
would have ended. This change was
also effective upon enactment.
The new rule regarding the start of the penalty period
has senior advocates up in arms. They
worry that thousands (they've even said millions) of Americans will be denied
critical long-term care because of gifts they made unwittingly to grandkids or
charities. Long-term care providers
are also concerned they'll end up providing charity care for hapless residents
who transferred assets without realizing the consequences.
Neither problem will occur.
Assets transferred for any other reason than to qualify
for Medicaid are not penalizable. Gifts
to families or charities for other reasons have been and remain exempt under
federal law. Furthermore, asset
transfers that would incur a penalty are much less likely to occur now than
before because the "half-a-loaf" divestment strategy no longer works.
Medicaid planning attorneys who recommend it will be vulnerable to
malpractice lawsuits. The far more
likely scenario is that instead of transferring their assets to qualify for
Medicaid as before, people will preserve their wealth and use it to pay
privately for long-term care. That's
good for seniors because private payors have more choices among a wider range of
better long-term care services than Medicaid recipients do.
It's good for long-term care providers because they desperately need more
private patients paying market rates for their services to make up for
Medicaid's dismally low reimbursement rates.
Undue
Hardship Waivers
"But what if?," insist the senior advocates and long-term care
providers. Could it actually happen
that some people would intentionally or unwittingly transfer assets for less
than fair market value for the purpose of qualifying for Medicaid and incur an
eligibility penalty at the very time they need long-term care?
It's not likely now that the incentive to divest assets has been removed,
but of course it is possible. If
that happens, however, the DRA has also strengthened provisions in the law which
provide for "undue hardship waivers" in such cases.
If a transfer of assets eligibility penalty would deny
medical care or food, clothing, shelter, or other necessities of life to a
Medicaid applicant, then the applicant, the applicant's representative, and even
the long-term care facility itself may request a hardship waiver allowing the
applicant to receive Medicaid benefits in spite of the improper, penalizable
asset transfer. The law even
permits payments to long-term care facilities while Medicaid eligibility is
pending for up to 30 days. State
Medicaid programs are required to notify recipients of the hardship waiver
option. Finally, members of
Congress and the American Health Care Association have appealed to the Centers
for Medicare and Medicaid Services to build strong protections into the
regulations that will be published to implement the Deficit Reduction Act's
stricter eligibility provisions. (Endnote
2) The devastating consequences
predicted by opponents of the Deficit Reduction Act before and after its passage
are thus highly unlikely to occur.
Rounding
Down and Combining Asset Transfers
The Deficit Reduction Act made two additional changes to the rules
bearing on asset transfers that warrant explanation.
State Medicaid programs are now barred from "rounding down"
fractional periods of ineligibility to determine asset transfer ineligibility
periods. Before the DRA, the
transfer of assets penalty began at the date of the transfer.
This meant that someone could give away an amount equal to the average
cost of a nursing home in the state at the beginning of each month and only
incur an eligibility penalty equal to the duration of that current month.
Some states rounded down the amount of assets transferred to qualify for
Medicaid to the next lowest whole amount equal to the average cost of a nursing
home. Thus, in such states, a
person could give away one dollar less than double the nursing home cost and
only be penalized for the single, current month of eligibility.
Federal law no longer allows states to round down in this way. Therefore, this provision eliminates the loophole that
allowed states to ignore otherwise penalizable asset transfers up to double the
average monthly price of a private nursing home minus one dollar.
Why would states have allowed that?
Who knows, but some did. Not
anymore.
In a related provision, the DRA permits states to treat multiple asset
transfers as a single transfer and to begin the penalty period on the earliest
date that would apply to such transfers. States
may thus combine multiple fractional asset transfers to make one cumulative
uncompensated value for the purpose of determining the transfer of assets
penalty. This prevents penalties
for fractional transfers from running concurrently thus reducing the effective
penalty. As explained above,
stronger undue hardship waivers and, one might add, good public service business
practices, protect Medicaid applicants and recipients from possible but unlikely
negative consequences that could occur as a result of these changes.
The
Home Equity Exemption
The other major change to Medicaid long-term care eligibility enacted by
the Deficit Reduction Act is a reduction in the program's home equity exemption.
Previously, Medicaid recipients could retain a home and all contiguous
property of unlimited value while receiving long-term care benefits from the
welfare program. The DRA places a
limit of $500,000 on home equity, although it allows states at their option to
increase that limit to $750,000. Critical
to note is that this new limit does not apply if a spouse or a minor or disabled
child remain living in the home. Starting
in 2011, the new home equity exemption limit will increase annually with the
Consumer Price Index. Reverse
mortgages may be used to reduce home equity down to a level at which the
homeowner can qualify for Medicaid. The
new home equity limit applies for Medicaid applications filed on or after
January 1, 2006.
One might reasonably ask why a $500,000 limit on home equity for Medicaid
eligibility matters much. After
all, the median home equity of elderly Americans is only $85,516.
(Endnote 3) Unfortunately, a
common Medicaid estate planning strategy is to "hide money in the
home." In other words, people
can convert a countable resource like cash into an exempt resource simply by
investing the money in home improvements or even buying a more expensive house.
For the first time since its enactment in 1965, Medicaid now limits that
method of qualifying for Medicaid. Although
the median home value for seniors is low, the prime candidates for Medicaid
planning have homes worth $250,000 to $400,000 which they mostly own free and
clear of mortgage debt.
Obviously, to have full effect, the home equity exemption
needs to be lowered much further to discourage dependency on Medicaid by people
of substantial wealth and to encourage the use of home equity conversion to pay
for long-term care in lieu of going on welfare. Ironically, the United Kingdom--another European socialized
health care system--only allows a home exemption of around $36,000 for people
who receive publicly financed long-term care.
Over time, as Medicaid-driven budget pressures at the state and federal
levels increase, the program's home equity exemption will undoubtedly drop
considerably, ultimately to $50,000--the level recommended already last year by
the National Governors Association--or even lower.
Until such a low limit on home equity is applied, it is
unlikely that the markets for reverse mortgages and long-term care insurance
will reach their full potentials. Why
encumber your home equity if it is not at risk for long-term care?
Why purchase insurance against the risk of expenses for which the
government will pay while protecting your biggest asset?
One similar eligibility loophole that the DRA left untouched is the
exemption of a business including the capital and cash flow in unlimited
amounts. One can expect the
practice of sheltering of assets in a business to increase now that the
sheltering of assets in a home has been limited, however slightly.
Annuities
for Self-Impoverishment
In addition to the big changes in Medicaid eligibility rules bearing on
asset transfers and the home equity exemption, the DRA plugged a number of other
"loopholes" previously used to qualify for the program by means of
artificial self-impoverishment. Medicaid's
treatment of "annuities and other large transactions" is one such
area. Medicaid planners and some
annuity salespeople have long recommended "Medicaid-friendly
annuities." The idea is that
people who need long-term care but don't want to pay for it themselves may
convert a large countable asset (for example, $100,000 cash) into an annuitized
income stream and qualify for Medicaid. Such
a conversion of wealth from an asset to income is not a penalizable
"transfer of assets for less than fair market value for the purpose of
qualifying for Medicaid" because the cash flow from the annuity is equal in
economic value to the cash in exchange for which it was obtained.
It is a value for value exchange. The
new income from the annuity must be considered in determining Medicaid
eligibility, but income is rarely an obstacle to eligibility because most states
have "medically needy" eligibility systems in which medical expenses
including private nursing home costs are deducted from income before determining
eligibility. The remainder of the
states have "income cap" systems in which "Miller income
trusts" can be used to the same effect.
The annuity can also be in a community spouse's name which makes it even
more attractive.
The Deficit Reduction Act put a number of obstacles in the way of using
annuities as a Medicaid planning technique, although it didn't eliminate the
practice altogether. The DRA
requires Medicaid recipients and community spouses to disclose annuities at the
time of eligibility determination and at every periodic recertification of
eligibility, which usually occurs annually or semi-annually.
Beginning with the date of enactment of the new law, the state must be
named as remainder beneficiary for annuities held by Medicaid recipients or
their spouses. State Medicaid
programs must notify the issuer of the annuity of the state's status as
remainder beneficiary. At their
option, states may require annuity issuers to report income or principal
withdrawals from the annuity. States
may then deny Medicaid eligibility based on such withdrawals if they exceed
allowable limits. Hence forward,
purchase of an annuity is a penalizable transfer of assets unless the state is
listed as remainder beneficiary in first position for at least the total amount
of Medicaid payments made on behalf of the recipient or in second position to a
community spouse or minor or disabled child for the same amount.
Spousal annuities remain an option under certain circumstances.
But the message about annuities in the Deficit Reduction Act is clear:
the door is closing on the abuse of annuities as a means to divert
responsibility for long-term care financing from affluent individuals to
taxpayers at the expense of Medicaid's long-term care safety net for the poor.
Transfer
of Assets Before Income
The Deficit Reduction Act eliminates the "transfer assets before
income" technique of Medicaid planning and imposes a mandatory "income
first rule." This topic is
complicated and requires some historical background and explanation to
understand fully. But in a
nutshell, state Medicaid programs must henceforth apply the
"income-first" rule and not the "assets-first" option to
community spouses who appeal for an increased resource allowance to maximize
assets invested to meet their minimum income requirements.
In more detail, community spouses of institutionalized
Medicaid recipients are allowed to retain half the couple's joint assets not to
exceed $99,540. This is called the
Community Spouse Resource Allowance or CSRA.
Community spouses may also retain a Minimum Monthly Maintenance Needs
Allowance (MMMNA) which has an upper limit of $2,488.50.
These figures for the CSRA and MMMNA are current as of 2006 and increase
annually with the Consumer Price Index. The
CSRA and MMMNA were introduced in the Medicare Catastrophic Coverage Act of 1988
(MCCA '88) in order to put an end to the problem of "spousal
impoverishment." Originally, the CSRA was limited to $60,000 and the MMMNA,
$1,500.
People in nursing homes on Medicaid must contribute most
of their income, excluding a small personal needs allowance, toward the cost of
their care. Before MCCA '88,
community spouses of institutionalized Medicaid recipients were only allowed to
retain their own income (in any amount) or a portion of their spouse's income
not to exceed the Supplemental Security Income (SSI) monthly allowance.
The SSI allowance is $603 as of 2006, but it was only approximately $350
in 1988. Because community spouses
are predominantly women and because women of the older generation tend to have
less income than men, spousal impoverishment most often occurred when a husband
was institutionalized on Medicaid and his wife was only allowed to retain the
SSI monthly allowance of roughly $350 per month, hardly enough to survive.
MCCA '88 ended spousal impoverishment by increasing the community
spouse's asset and income limits as described above.
Here's how the Deficit Reduction Act changes that arrangement.
Prior to the DRA, state Medicaid programs could allow community spouses
to increase their income up to the MMMNA in either of two ways.
The "income first" rule required them to take income from the
institutionalized spouse first before taking assets. This approach resulted in Medicaid receiving less of the
recipient's income to offset his cost of care but it left excess assets
vulnerable to resource limits. The
other "asset first" approach allowed the community spouse to receive
extra assets from the institutionalized spouse in addition to the CSRA up to a
total amount the interest on which would bring her up to the MMMNA.
Medicaid planners sought out opportunities to utilize this "asset
first" approach. They routinely advised their clients to find the lowest
possible interest rate returns in order to maximize the amount of assets
transferable from the institutionalized to the community spouse to bring the
latter up to her MMMNA. It was
reportedly commonplace for families to be able to shelter up to several hundreds
of thousands of dollars from Medicaid asset eligibility limits in this way.
The Deficit Reduction Act prohibits this practice and mandates the
"income first" rule. Unless
Medicaid applicants find other ways to shelter or divest excess assets, this
change should encourage more people to spend their money for long-term care in
the private marketplace instead of gaming Medicaid to preserve large amounts.
CCRCs,
SCINs, and Life Estates
Finally, the Deficit Reduction Act curtailed three additional Medicaid
planning techniques. The new law
allows state Medicaid programs to count Continuing Care Retirement Community (CCRC)
and Life Care Community (LCC) admission contracts as countable resources. CCRCs and LCCs usually charge entrance fees which are
sometimes refundable if the resident never needs the high-cost nursing home care
for which the fees are intended to provide.
Medicaid planners had found a way to shelter such fees thus allowing
residents to get the money back AND get Medicaid to pay for their nursing home
care. This was a serious problem
for the retirement communities because of Medicaid's low reimbursement rates,
which are often less than the cost of providing the care. The DRA permits states to eliminate this eligibility loophole
which Medicaid planners employed to evade spend-down requirements at long-term
care facilities' expense.
The DRA changes Medicaid eligibility rules to include certain funds used
to purchase a promissory note, loan or mortgage among countable assets unless
repayment terms are actuarially sound, provide for equal payments and prohibit
the cancellation of the balance upon the death of the lender.
This provision makes funds used to purchase certain promissory notes,
loans or mortgages vulnerable to the transfer of assets penalty. It stops
the ever-popular Medicaid planning device known as SCINs (self-canceling
installment notes) and other similar loopholes previously used to qualify for
Medicaid. Last but not least, the
DRA treats the purchase of a "life
estate" as a penalizable asset transfer unless the purchaser resides in the
home for at least one year after the date of purchase.
So ends the hit list of Medicaid planning gambits successfully targeted
by the Deficit Reduction Act.
Effective
Dates
Now, a word about effective dates. The
provisions of the DRA are effective as indicated in the law except if state
legislation is required to implement them.
If so, then the new rules take effect "the first day of the first
calendar quarter beginning after the close of the first regular session of the
State legislature that begins after the date of the enactment of this Act."
Medicaid planners are touting this potential delay of implementing these
new rules as one last opportunity to plan for Medicaid, a Medicaid planning fire
sale as it were. Here's how one Medicaid planning publication put it:
"The bottom line is if you have been hesitating about seeing an
attorney about long-term care planning, hesitate no longer.
If you have considered protecting some assets for your loved ones in case
you later require long-term care, you should contact a qualified elder law
attorney now." (Endnote 4)
This is precisely the sort of abuse--lucrative for lawyers, but
devastating for taxpayers, Medicaid, and poor people legitimately dependent on
public assistance--that the Deficit Reduction Act attempted, evidently with some
considerable success, to curtail.
The
DRA and the Long-Term Care Partnership Program
The second major set of provisions of interest to us in the Deficit
Reduction Act authorizes expansion of the Long-Term Care Partnership Program.
The LTC Partnership Program began as an experimental project funded by
the Robert Woods Johnson Foundation in the late 1980s.
It was the brainchild of Dr. Mark Meiners, an economist who did the early
research that established long-term care as an insurable risk and helped to
launch the product and the market as viable economic enterprises.
Dr. Meiners recognized that Medicaid crowded out most demand for
long-term care insurance. He
reckoned that a positive incentive to buy the protection might prevail where
Medicaid's toothless spend-down rules had little effect.
He designed the partnership program to provide just such an incentive by
forgiving the Medicaid spend-down requirement in an amount equal to the amount
of insurance protection purchased and used.
The program differed in New York somewhat, but conceptually that was the
idea and the way the program was implemented in Connecticut, Indiana and
California. For example, buy $100,000 worth of long-term care insurance,
use it up, and qualify for Medicaid while keeping $102,000 of your own money
instead of having to "spend down" to the ostensible limit of $2,000
otherwise required.
All went well at first. More
and more states were gearing up to implement the LTC partnership program as the
decade of the 1990s began. But then
came a devastating blow. When
Congress mandated Medicaid estate recoveries in the Omnibus Budget
Reconciliation Act of 1993 (OBRA '93), Congressman Henry Waxman (D, CA) who was
then Chairman of the House Energy and Commerce Committee (the germane committee
for Medicaid in the U.S. House of Representatives) refused to exempt any future
LTC partnership states from the new requirement.
Thus, while new partnerships states might exempt assets for purposes of
eligibility, they could not exempt the same assets from estate recovery. Figuring that this change eliminated the LTC partnership's
incentive to buy insurance, states stopped implementing new partnerships and the
program languished until now. The
Deficit Reduction Act repealed the "Waxman amendment" and authorized
new state LTC partnership programs to exempt protected assets from estate
recovery as well as from eligibility limits.
Everyone expects the popular LTC partnership programs to expand rapidly
nationwide with that obstacle removed.
While the DRA removes the major obstacle to new partnership programs, it
also imposes some new requirements. To
qualify for the partnership program, long-term care insurance policies must be
"tax qualified," meaning they need to qualify for the limited tax
deduction authorized by the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act
of 1996. They must meet the
National Association of Insurance Commissioners' model regulations and Act as of
October 2000. They must provide for
benefit increases or options especially for younger insureds.
The DRA mandates reporting for insurers and training for agents who
market partnership policies. There
are minimum data set reporting requirements to ensure proper evaluation of the
programs. By January 1, 2007, the
Secretary of the Department of Health and Human Services is supposed to publish
"standards for uniform reciprocal recognition," that is to say
portability guidelines that will help to make partnership benefits available in
one state equally available in others. The
Secretary is also required to report annually to the Congress on the LTC
partnership programs' progress. Finally,
the DRA establishes a National Clearinghouse for Long-Term Care Information,
with funding of $3 million per year
from 2006 to 2010, to help educate consumers about the risk and cost of
long-term care and the importance of buying private insurance protection.
Likely
Impact of LTC Partnerships Enhanced by Medicaid Eligibility Changes
The long-term care insurance industry is clearly thrilled by this
expansion of the LTC partnership program. It
will enhance the market for their product.
Long-term care providers are also enthusiastic, although less so,
inasmuch as the benefits of having more insured private payers someday in the
future won't benefit providers as soon as it will help insurers.
Ironically, however, LTC insurers seem to have hardly noticed the changes
in Medicaid eligibility and LTC providers actually opposed one of the most
important modifications, e.g. the change in the date of the asset transfer
penalty.
Why ironic? Without
the provisions of the DRA that tightened Medicaid long-term care eligibility, it
is unlikely that expansion of the long-term care partnership program would have
had much effect. Studies conducted
of the partnerships programs in the four original states indicate that they
helped expand the long-term care insurance market on the margin, but they hardly
made a qualitative difference as compared to the market for the product in
other, non-partnership states. (Endnote
5) Think about it.
Why would someone buy private long-term care insurance many years in
advance of needing long-term care, an eventuality about which most consumers are
in denial anyway, simply to avoid a Medicaid spend-down liability that didn't
really exist in the first place? The
answer is: they wouldn't and for the most part they didn't.
That's why the original partnership programs were only marginally
successful.
The big news now is that Medicaid does finally have,
thanks to the DRA, much stronger limits on long-term care eligibility.
Therefore, the long-term care partnership's asset forgiveness benefit,
both on the front end for eligibility and on the back end from estate recovery,
is far greater than it used to be. We
have every reason to believe that the partnership program will be far more
successful now that it has been in the past.
Of course, that expectation depends entirely on whether or not the
Medicaid eligibility provisions of the DRA are aggressively implemented,
enforced and publicized.
The
DRA and Home and Community-Based Services Under Medicaid
The third and final major set of provisions in the Deficit Reduction Act
bearing on long-term care relates to the expansion of home and community-based
services (HCBS) funded by Medicaid. The
DRA makes HCBS an option coverable under the Medicaid state plan without a
special waiver as previously required. States
may limit enrollment in the program to control expenditures.
They can also elect not to comply with "statewideness," the
requirement governing most services offered by Medicaid which says they must be
made available at substantially the same level and in the same form everywhere
in the state. Receipt of home and
community-based services will no longer require that the Medicaid recipient have
a medical need for nursing home level of care in order to qualify for HCBS, an
ironical contradiction seemingly inimical to recipients' best interests, that
was mandated under the waiver programs. At
their option, states may allow recipients to purchase and control their own care
thus extending the idea of consumer-driven health care into the arena of
welfare-financed long-term care. States
must provide for quality control of HCBS. These
provisions are effective January 1, 2007.
This is a good thing, right? Absolutely.
One of the biggest problems with Medicaid-financed long-term care in the
past has been its "institutional bias." Medicaid paid mostly for nursing home care and much less for
home care over the years. That
imbalance has been changing for a decade or more but still exists. But now, on the other hand, consider this.
Won't Medicaid be more attractive when it provides home
care, assisted living and other community-based services, not just nursing home
care? Won't people be more likely
to search for ways to qualify for Medicaid by means of artificial
self-impoverishment and consulting Medicaid planners? Won't they be less likely to buy long-term care insurance,
which requires big premiums to qualify for benefit payments covering HCBS that
Medicaid will now be offering for free? Yes,
expansion of Medicaid to cover HCBS more liberally than in the past could have
caused all those negative consequences, except for the fact that the DRA also
tightened Medicaid's eligibility limits. Therefore, once again, just as the new constraints on
Medicaid long-term care eligibility promise to enhance the effectiveness of the
long-term care partnership program, they will also mitigate any damage that
might have been done by expanding the program's coverage of HCBS and making
Medicaid therefore more attractive as a long-term care payor.
Medicaid will be a better, more attractive program for a smaller number
of recipients who genuinely need its help.
Conclusion
The Deficit Reduction Act is an important step forward toward improving
America's long-term care service delivery and financing system.
It eliminates some of the perverse incentives in Medicaid that crowded
out long-term care insurance and home equity conversion as long-term care payors.
It adds positive incentives for people to plan early, and save, invest or
insure for long-term care. It makes
Medicaid a better program for people genuinely in need by enhancing the
availability of home and community-based services which most people prefer.
The job is not finished, however.
Medicaid needs to be further reformed to lengthen the transfer of assets
look back period, to lower the home equity exemption, to place a limit on the
wide-open business exemption, to eliminate the shameful "spousal
refusal" gambit which encourages people to abandon their spouses in order
to obtain welfare benefits for them, and to close the dozens of other loopholes
that continue to trap people on public assistance unnecessarily.
The DRA is a vital beginning, although only a start.
Let me close with a warning.
If the Deficit Reduction Act is not implemented by the states, enforced
by the federal government, publicized by the media, and sold by LTC insurance
agents and reverse mortgage lenders, it may fail to achieve its full potential
for improving long-term care service delivery and financing.
The Center for Long-Term Care Reform is dedicated to ensuring that the
DRA does achieve its full potential in that regard.
We invite everyone of good will to join with us to make the most of this
wonderful victory in the fight for rational long-term care policy.
Stephen A. Moses is president of the Center for
Long-Term Care Reform in Seattle, Washington.
The Center's mission is to ensure quality long-term care for all
Americans. Steve Moses writes,
speaks and consults throughout the United States on long-term care policy.
He is the author of the study "Aging America's Achilles' Heel:
Medicaid Long-Term Care," published by the Cato Institute (www.cato.org).
Learn more at www.centerltc.com
or email smoses@centerltc.com.
Endnote
1: The report of the
Conference Committee of the House of Representatives and the Senate for the
Deficit Reduction Act of 2005 is available at http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-bin/cpquery/?sel=DOC&&item=&r_n=hr362.109&&&sid=cp109lxkwK&&refer=&&&db_id=cp109&&hd_count=&.
The Conference Report describes the provisions of the original bills
passed by the House and Senate and the provisions of the compromise reached in
the Conference Committee and ultimately passed by both Houses in identical form
with the exception of the clerical error mentioned above.
Endnote 2: AHCA
Press Release, "Long Term Care Associations Backing U.S. Rep. Peter King's
Effort to Ensure Nation's Most Vulnerable Seniors Protected During DRA
Implementation Period, March 28, 2006, http://www.ahca.org/news/nr060328a.htm.
Endnote 3: He,
Wan, Manisha Sengupta, Victoria A. Velkoff , and Kimberly A. DeBarros, U.S.
Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, P23-209, 65+ in the United States:
2005, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC, 2005, Table 4-10:
Median Net Worth and Median Net Worth Excluding Home Equity for
Households by Age of Householder and Monthly Household Income Quintile: 2000, p.
108, http://www.census.gov/prod/2006pubs/p23-209.pdf.
Endnote 4: ElderLaw
Answers,
"Congress Passes Bill Containing Punitive New Medicaid Transfer Rules"
at http://www.elderlawanswers.com/resources/article.asp?id=5221§ion=4.
Endnote 5: Nelda
McCall, editor, Who Will Pay for Long Term
Care?: Insights from the
Partnership Programs, Health Administration Press, Chicago, Illinois, 2001.
|